RE: [PP-DIALOG] Definition of Reasonable Rates
No Gil, no surprise that you agree with Scott. I do
appreciate though the time it takes each of you to present your positions in
these e-mails. Thank you.
Gil and Scott,
I wonder how adding the phrase "before the adoption of the
standard" in this definition of reasonable rates, terms and conditions would
have helped Cisco in the single event Gil mentions so often of receiving some
160 patent license offers of 1% each that more than doubled the cost of the
product?
Was that situation for a particular standard? Which
one? What was the product?
How would this new definition work for a company, such as
TI and others, that typically does not license (as licensee or licensor)
individual patents, but often enters into 5-10 year field of use, portfolio
licenses with competitors based on several business and technical considerations
in addition to royalty rate? These companies enter into these licenses
typically after some standards are adopted and before other standards are
adopted.
I read the paper by Swanson and Baumol (73 Antitrust L J)
and with all the limiting assumptions they made, they did not appear to address
the situation described in the preceding paragraph. Are you considering
the IEEE using the royalty computing equations suggested in this
paper?
Would this definition of "before the adoption of the
standard" exclude consideration of the factors from Georgia-Pacific or other
factors, including a refusal to take or give a license? Who would
decide?
Would this refined
definition be required to be used in licensing between only IEEE member
companies? How would IEEE know? What would IEEE do if it was not
followed? What about an IEEE member company licensing with a company that
is not an IEEE member?
As y'all know, TI is not
completely against ex ante disclosures. In the WWiSE proposal for IEEE
802.11n, we voluntarily tried to make an ex ante royalty free disclosure so the
working group could consider both the technical and business merits of the
proposal. We learned however that some people in IEEE considered our ex
ante offer improper, because it made the business merits, shall I
say, "transparent".
Regards,
Larry
It probably won't
surprise observers of this debate to learn that I agree with the
points that Scott makes below. To pick up on a point that came up in
the discussion of ex ante on the ABA Sci Tech Committee listserv,
supporters of ex ante view the definition of RAND as a second-best
solution. Defining RAND is necessary only for SDOs that don't "jump
the chasm in one leap" by moving to a world in which participants
disclosing patents to a standards working group state up front the
terms under which they will license those patents. The proposal now in
front of IEEE-SA identifies ex ante disclosure as only one of a number of
options, and retaining RAND as another option. It therefore becomes
necessary to go down the road of defining what RAND means.
I also agree with
Scott that atempting to define RAND does not amount to rewriting patent
law. Rather it is a recognition both (a) that the existing
Georgia-Pacific test for determining the reasonableness
of patent royalties is not sufficiently precise to give
businesspeople the predictability they need to decide whether to implement
a standards-compliant product, and (b) that there is a broad range of views
among companies participating in standard-setting as to what obligations a RAND
commitment imposes on the patentholder that makes
it.
Scott has captured
well the first aspect of the indeterminacy of RAND. As to the second, the
motion to dismiss recently filed by Qualcomm in the Broadcom v.
Qualcomm antitrust lawsuit is instructive. In moving to
dismiss Broadcom's antitrust claim, Qualcomm, which both parties agree
committed to license certain of its patents on RAND terms in commitments made in
various standards bodies, nevertheless characterizes Broadcom's
allegation that Qualcomm has imposed allegedly unreasonable licensing term
as protesting that Qualcomm is charging too much for the use of its
patents. To quote from Qualcomm's motion, "[c]harging what the market will
bear, however, is not an anticompetitive or unreasonable act."
Broadcom v. Qualcomm, Civil Action No. 05-3550 (MLC), D.N.J.,
Memorandum in Support of Defendant's Motion to Dismiss at 18 (emphasis
supplied) (filed December 9, 2005). I read Qualcomm's argument to be
that a RAND commitment imposes no limitation al all on the acknowledged right of
a patentholder to "[c]harg[e] what the market will bear."
I am not -- either
for myself or on behalf of Cisco -- taking a position on the merits of the
Broadcom v. Qualcomm litigation or the correctness as a matter
either of antitrust law or patent law of Qualcomm's apparent interpretation
of the RAND obligations it assumed. Nevertheless, it seems to me that if
Qualcomm's view is vindicated then the question of whether RAND has
any meaning is, at the very least, open to debate. Viewed
against that backdrop, the proposal under consideration by IEEE PatComm to
add definition to the meaning of RAND as used within IEEE should be
welcomed by all companies that participate in standard
setting.
Gil Ohana
Director, Antitrust and
Competition
Cisco Systems, Inc.
300 E. Tasman Drive
MS 10/2
San Jose, CA 95134
United States of
America
Phone: +1 408 525
2853
Mobile: +1 408 203
5301
E-mail:
gilohana@cisco.com
1. Does the IEEE need to define
“reasonable rates, terms and conditions?”
A definition of the kind
that Don has suggested would be a critical clarification of IEEE’s existing
policy of asking patent owners to make a statement about their licensing
intentions. If the IEEE were to require disclosure of and commitment to actual
licensing terms as part of each RAND commitment, a definition of “reasonable
rates, terms and conditions” would be significantly less important. But without
such license term disclosure, going forward without a definition of “reasonable
rates, terms and conditions” greatly limits the value of much of the current
effort by PatCom. The IEEE bylaws seek an assurance in terms of “reasonable
rates, with reasonable terms and conditions”; it is, important that the IEEE be
clear as to what it is asking, and therefore, it is entirely appropriate that
the IEEE to say what it means when it asks for such an assurance. This is not a
matter of rewriting patent law; it is about enhancing the quality and utility of
information that IEEE now expects patent owners to
provide.
A definition of the kind
Don has suggested is an important adjunct to policy changes that encourage (but
do not require) ex ante disclosure of a maximum royalty rate and/or ex ante
provision of a proposed license agreement. If a standard is adopted in a manner
that makes a given patent essential to its implementation after the patent
owner’s maximum royalty rate and other material terms have been disclosed to SDO
participants who are also prospective licensees, the disclosed terms are likely
to be viewed as “reasonable” based on the implied conclusion of the informed
voters on the proposed standard in question. However, where patent owners
decline to disclose their terms prior to voting, improved clarity in the meaning
of the words used in the assurance could reduce the likelihood of subsequent
complex litigation over ex post license demands. In these circumstances, a
definition of the kind Don has suggested would become a desirable aid to dispute
resolution. It would be a test distinctly different from existing case law that
is used to determine “reasonable royalties” for assessment of damages in
infringement litigation under the so-called “Georgia-Pacific” factors, which
many legal commentators agree can be less than helpful, and which are generally
applied at the time infringement begins, which is misplaced in the standards
context. That test is not appropriate for determining what is “reasonable” in
the context of a patent essential to implement what is intended to be an “open”
industry standard adopted at a time when (a) alternatives to the solution being
considered for the standard were available to the decision-makers; and (b) those
decision-makers expressly relied on the patent owner’s RAND commitment in
rejecting those alternatives in favor of the patented
solution.
The IEEE PatCom should not
presume that its adopted definition is necessarily appropriate for All US SDOs
or for the rest of the world; rather, the Committee should adopt a definition
that suits its own purposes as guidance on the meaning and intent of patent
assurances for the IEEE’s standards. The greater transparency and reduced
litigation risk that these measures would bring to IEEE proceedings as compared
to other SDOs lacking such measures would become a distinct competitive
advantage for the IEEE, strengthening its status as an important forum for IT
standard-setting activities.
It is undesirable to let “each judge in
each court in each case define” what is meant in the assurance statements made
to the IEEE. Like clarity in the specification of the standards themselves,
predictability regarding costs entailed in adopting any given solution,
prominently including required license fees, is critical to the evolution and
growth of new markets based on new technologies that IEEE standards are intended
to enable. Unpredictability and the resulting heightened risk of litigation that
can stall market development are contrary to the IEEE’s fundamental objectives
as a forum for IT standard-setting activity.
2. If the IEEE does define it,
what should the definition be?
Don’s definition makes good sense.
Prominent economists who have written extensively about patent issues in IT
standards contexts have suggested similar definitions. See, for example, Shapiro
& Varian, Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy at p.
241 (1999): reasonable royalties are “the royalties that the patent-holder could
obtain in open, up-front competition with other technologies, not the royalties
that the patent holder can extract once other participants are effectively
locked in to use technology covered by the patents”; Farrell & Shapiro,
Intellectual Property, Competition, and Information Technology at p. 30 (Berkely
Working Paper, 2004): fair and reasonable licensing terms are “normally best
measured by adopters’ willingness to pay . . . when they know their alternatives
and have not yet made investments specific to that technology.” See more
generally the excellent new article by Daniel Swanson and William Baumol on
Reasonable and Nondiscriminatory (RAND) Royalties, Standards Selection, and
Control of Market Power, 73 Antitrust Law Journal 1 (2005).
--
Scott
______________________________
Scott K. Peterson
Senior
Counsel
Hewlett-Packard Company
scott.k.peterson@hp.com
OK... the holiday season is over. Time to
throw some meat to the wolves...
One of the issues
the IEEE is trying to address is a definition of "reasonable rates, terms and
conditions" Other than the issue of the interpretation of "arms-length"
from a cultural perspective, here's where I think we left it:
Reasonable rates, terms and conditions
shall mean rates, terms and conditions that a willing licensor and a willing
licensee would agree to in an arms-length negotiation before the adoption of the
standard, taking into consideration any alternative technologies and any
alternative implementation methods which eliminate the essentiality of the
patent claim(s).
If we could, let's only consider
two aspects of this:
1) Does the IEEE need to define
this?
- Is this already
defined in some case law?
-
Should this be defined identically for all US SDOs, i.e., should it come ex
cathedra from ANSI? If so, what about the rest of the world?
- Is letting each judge in each
court in each case define it really a workable solution, i.e. is it OK not to be
able to predict the answer for each case?
2) If the
IEEE does define it, what should the definition be?
Please try to keep the argument at a level even us non-lawyers can
understand (not too much latin ;>)) Any pointers to cases should be to
something on the web (or attached) so we can all read it.
***************************************************************************
Don Wright
don@lexmark.com
f.wright@ieee.org / f.wright@computer.org
Director of Standards
Lexmark International
Past Chair, IEEE SA Standards Board
740 New Circle Rd
Chair, Patent Committee IEEE SASB
Lexington, Ky 40550
Member-at-large, IEEE CS SAB
859-825-4808 (phone)
Member, IEEE-ISTO Board of Directors
603-963-8352 (fax)
Member, W3C Advisory Committee
***************************************************************************