Thread Links | Date Links | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Thread Prev | Thread Next | Thread Index | Date Prev | Date Next | Date Index |
I've seen conflicting positions in this dialog about the voluntariness of disclosure of terms. It leaves me confused what is expected policy. The package of proposals appear designed to not only provide licensing position options under an LOA, but an assurance of guaranteed commercial prices and licensing terms in advance of the standard being available to the general public. If these proposals move IEEE to a regime that requires licenses or mandates an assurance of a license or blanket license as a condition of participation or contribution, IEEE may want to have outside counsel advise it further about imposing that type of policy agreement.
I believe that the rules changes being proposed for consideration by PatCom only provide for the assurance of commercial prices and licensing terms as one option that a participant that contributes what it believes are essential patents may provide. As a supporter of the changes, the way I see them working is that the other participants will draw their own conclusions from the choice that their fellow participant makes. Some of them may be more inclined to vote in favor of the inclusion of a particular technical contribution in a final IEEE standard if they are assured in advance that the technology will be available to them on set terms. For others the existence of a detailed licensing commitment may matter less.
I will let IEEE comment on the legal advice it may have received from IEEE counsel. As you may be aware, there have been a number of recent statements from US and European competition authorities that have expressed the view that, to quote FTC Chairman Deborah Majoras, “a patent holder’s voluntary and unilateral disclosure of its maximum royalty rate … is highly unlikely to raise antitrust scrutiny." (Chairman Majoras' speech is available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/majoras/050923stanford). I assume that this and other pronouncements by the Justice Department Antitrust Division, the Federal Trade Commission, and the European Union have given IEEE's antitrust counsel comfort with the proposed rules changes, but again, they can speak for themselves.
I would also like to know how voluntary
disclosure will work in practice:
> Will IEEE expect and
request or call for public disclosure of confidential rates/terms from members?
> Will IEEE allow its work groups to take any negative presumptions
without disclosed terms? How is that voluntary?
> Can IEEE PatCom reject
the terms if they don't satisfy some criteria it determines appropriate?
> Rates are much more complicated than fixed lumpsum fees. How will
maximum rates be useful to IEEE process? Will they mislead rather than
clarify?
On the first question, it is not at all unsual for patentholders to disclose a licensing program including detailed terms. Once disclosed, of course, those terms become non-confidential. Also, to go back to an earlier point, the disclosure of terms is only one option that a patentholder may choose. If it wishes to keep its detailed tersm confidential, it is free to check the RAND box and invite questions from licensees regarding its terms.
As to "negative presumptions" that working groups may draw from a failure of a patentholder to disclose terms, my view is that individual participants may well draw a negative presumption. In the situation in which there are two substitute technologies competing for inclusion in a standard, the fact that one of the submitters has disclosed concrete licensing terms may be seen by other participants as a reason, all other things being equal, to favor that technology. In my view, that's a good thing.
On your question regarding IEEE PatCom rejecting terms, I will let the PatCom members speak to this point, but my understanding is that there is no expectation that the adoption of the proposed rules changes would change the role of PatCom in reviewing LoAs, which will remain focused on compliance with the formal requirements of the IEEE rules, not the substance of particular LoAs.
As to your last point, I agree that licensing terms are more complicated than fixed lumpsum fees. My own view, however, is that more information about licensing intentions, made available earlier in the standards development process, is better than less information made available later. We can trust participants (and the counsel that represent them) to assist in untangling detailed disclosures.
> Is IEEE promoting licensing terms through its
LOA process by accepting and collecting license rates and T&Cs?
> If IEEE accepts by signing the
conditional terms under a LOA contract, has it agreed the terms are acceptable
or that it accepts the commercial conditions offered?
Here too, I will let IEEE speak for itself, but from the perspective of an observer of IEEE-SA and PatCom, I don't believe IEEE sees its role as "promoting" particular license terms or Ts and Cs. Likewise, I don't believe IEEE sees its role as validating the acceptability (or, for that matter, the "reasonableness") of proposed terms when it accepts an LoA.
> It's a simple example Don provides below, but why do Working Groups want/need to get into the level of the type of discussion alluded beyond the LOA?
Working groups, and individual members of working groups, may feel that more information regarding the terms under which particular essential patents will be provided assists them in making decisions regarding which technologies to support for inclusion in a standard. In a world where the only disclosure permitted is RAND, participants in a working group may feel that they are being asked to make those decisions without much information on which to compare alternative technology proposals or decide whether a marginal feature should be included as a mandatory part of a standard. This problem is compounded by the lack of consensus as to what either "reasonable" or "non-discriminatory" means, and specifically whether a commitment to license patents on "reasonable" terms in any way constrains a patentee from charging what the market will bear.
I agree that rules against discussion in meetings or development of the standard must be tight and strongly enforced by IEEE over its participants. Practically speaking, if terms are being requested to provide information to IEEE process, how will IEEE/engineer participants avoid the temptation of discussing them?
We agree that legal risks should be minimized in IEEE development process to the greatest extent possible. Participants should be able to expect that more certain, less risk environment and efficient process. I assume that this is a universal principal we all share and is not controversial. I don't see that it is in IEEE interests to discourage participation in development in any way due to uncertain process or risks of legal exposure.
Recent agency statements regarding the antitrust risks associated with disclosure of licensing terms may give a more realistic picture of the antitrust risks that IEEE and participants in IEEE working groups face from rules that permit disclosure of licensing terms. As to the desire for mitigation of legal risk, mitigation of legal risk is certainly one value that is important in the process of creating standards and commercializing standards-compliant products. Another value that Cisco and other companies that participate regularly in standard-setting believe is important is transparency in standard-setting, so that participants and other implementers of standards-compliant products know as early as possible what terms they will need to accept to implement standards-compliant products. The proposed rules changes regarding the definition of "reasonable" and the option to disclose at least a not-to-exceed royalty rate support that goal.
Thanks,
Michelle
From: Don
Wright [mailto:don@LEXMARK.COM]
Sent: Tuesday, March 14, 2006 5:32 PM
To:
PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: Re: [PP-DIALOG] Application
of per se rule to ex ante joint conduct
Amy:
The NEED for the change in what is now
clause 5.3.8 of the SASB Ops Manual will be a part of the discussion in agenda
item 6.2.6. I want PatCom to first decide whether to recommend allowing for the
voluntary disclosure of not-to-exceed rates before we propose any specific
language changes to 5.3.8. I don't want to waste everyone's time arguing about
the word changes there unless and until PatCom decides to recommend allowing the
disclosure.
I tend to agree with you that the language needs a little
"tightening" especially to insure group negotiation of pricing does not happen
in standards development meetings. On the other hand, I don't know how we can
forbid "discussion" in the meetings because that might preclude the
following:
Party 1: "We've committed to charge $10,000 to use our
patent"
Party 2: "Is that a one time fee, an annual fee or something
else?"
Party 1: "That's a one time fee."
Is the above a discussion?
Many would answer yes. Should it be forbidden? Personally, I don't think
so.
The question then becomes how to draw the line to allow for the above
and other similar interchanges while not allowing overt negotiation in standards
development meetings.
Should PatCom decide to recommend allowing
disclosure, I will welcome your suggestions for wording!
***************************************************************************
Don Wright
don@lexmark.com
f.wright@ieee.org / f.wright@computer.org
Director of
Standards
Lexmark International Past Chair, IEEE SA Standards Board
740 New Circle
Rd Chair, Patent Committee IEEE SASB
Lexington, Ky
40550 Member-at-large, IEEE CS SAB
859-825-4808
(phone) Member, IEEE-ISTO Board of Directors
603-963-8352
(fax) Member, W3C Advisory Committee
***************************************************************************
"Amy Marasco (LCA)"
<amarasco@microsoft.com>
Sent by:
PP-DIALOG@ieee.org
03/14/2006 07:43 PM
To:
<don@LEXMARK.COM>, <PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org>
cc:
Subject: RE: [PP-DIALOG]
Application of per se rule to ex ante joint
conduct
Don, will this clause be discussed at the upcoming PatCom meeting? With
all due respect, I am concerned that the wording in what was ops-manual-clause
5-3-9-v3.doc does not sufficiently delineate what activity is permitted when and
under what rules or parameters. For example, can proposed licensing terms be
discussed at a technical committee meeting and, if so, what are the procedures
governing that activity?
Many thanks,
Amy
From: Don
Wright [mailto:don@LEXMARK.COM]
Sent: Tuesday, March 14, 2006 1:44 PM
To:
PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: Re: [PP-DIALOG] Application
of per se rule to ex ante joint conduct
Amy, et al:
If you examine the agenda
for the December 5th PatCom Meeting (http://standards.ieee.org/board/pat/1205patagen.html) and look at the attachment to agenda item 5.3, you'll
find a ZIP file containing a document named ops-manual-clause-5-3-9-v3.doc. This
was proposed to address the issue of allowing the disclosure of licensing rates
but not allowing group negotiation of those rates at a standards development
meeting. PatCom could decide otherwise at any time but the committee has been
heading toward your (a) item below and not your (b) item.
(BTW: Due to
recent changes made in the Standards Board Operations Manual (http://standards.ieee.org/guides/opman/index.html), that clause is now
5.3.8)
"Amy Marasco (LCA)"
<amarasco@microsoft.com>
Sent by:
PP-DIALOG@ieee.org
03/12/2006 01:24 PM
To: "Skitol, Robert
A." <Robert.Skitol@DBR.COM>,
<PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org>
cc:
Subject:
RE: [PP-DIALOG] Application of per se rule to ex ante joint
conduct
I guess I am a little confused by the exchange of e-mails in
this
string. I am wondering if there is any degree of consensus around
the
notion that there is a difference between:
(a) the disclosure of
possible licensing terms (I say "possible" because
it is likely that not all
licensees will end up with the exact same
license), and
(b) the
discussion or negotiation of such terms as a group under the
auspices of a
standards body or as part of a standards-setting activity.
In other
words, is there any consensus that the PatComm should continue
to debate the
former, but that IEEE should expressly prohibit the
latter?
My reading
of the Hydrolevel case is that ASME was held liable because
it permitted
arguably anti-competitive conduct under its roof and under
its "apparent
authority". Doesn't it seem that, based on the Hydrolevel
and Golden Bridges
decisions, IEEE as a standards-setting organization
would better protect
itself and its members from possible antitrust
claims by prohibiting group
discussions or negotiations of commercial
licensing terms under its auspices
than by facilitating such activity?
Whatever IEEE determines are the
appropriate parameters, I think that
they should be spelled out very clearly
so that everyone understands
exactly what activity is permitted under IEEE's
rules and what is not.
I suspect that we can all agree that any ambiguity in
this regard would
be problematic.
-----Original
Message-----
From: Skitol, Robert A. [mailto:Robert.Skitol@DBR.COM]
Sent: Friday, March 10, 2006 9:36 PM
To:
PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: Re: [PP-DIALOG] Application of per se
rule to ex ante joint
conduct
Richard conflates the idea of
encouraging unilateral disclosure
of material license information -- the main
proposal now before the
IEEE's PatCom -- with "collective negotiation" and
"collusive" conduct
of the kind alleged in the Golden Bridges case, which
nobody is now
advocating for the IEEE. There is no credible basis whatsoever
for any
suggestion that the unilateral disclosure policy idea now before
PatCom
would increase antitrust risk or any other litigation exposure to
IEEE
or participants therein. To the extent the proposal would result
in
participants' disclosures of more license information during
standard
setting, it would do precisely what (a) Congress expressly
encouraged
SDOs to do in its enactment of the SDOAA two years ago (see
House
Report) and (b) both Assistant Attorney General Pate and FTC
Chairman
Majoras expressly encouraged SDOs to do in their speeches within
the
past year. Numerous published in-depth analyses (many cited in
Chairman
Majoras's speech) confirm the complete antitrust legality as well
as
affirmative desirability of more meaningful information
disclosures
along these lines. I am unaware of even a single contrary
analysis,
published or otherwise, that even begins to refute the
supportive
literature on this subject. As already noted, both enforcement
agencies
endorse the idea of an unqualifiedly "good" result from more rather
than
less material information being available during a
standard-setting
proceeding.
Richard's suggestion of an antitrust
problem with IEEE's adoption
of a definition of "reasonable" is equally
vacuous. IEEE already
encourages patent owners to make RAND commitments. How
can it suddenly
become an antitrust problem to explain or clarify what
RAND is intended
to mean for this purpose? Is the world better off with
controvery and
confusion over what RAND means? That is a formula for more
litigation of
the sort that is already burdening IEEE and other SDOs'
standards.
The irony is that, while policy changes of the kind now
under
consideration would entail no new legal risk of any kind, failure to
act
on them would leave unaddressed the all-too-real existing risk
of
abusive patent holdup conduct in connection with IEEE standards. This
is
a reality of the status quo that has already generated
litigation
messes, past and present. No need to get more specific about them
unless
Richard wants to do so. Suffice it to say that failure to address in
any
manner existing conditions enabling those disputes to have evolved
and
enabling more such disputes to arise in the future is nothing less
than
irresponsible.
Instead of chasing antitrust ghosts boo-hooing
about any move
forward, we should worry more about exposure from (a)
continued
collective suppression of highly material license information
during
standard setting; and (b) continued collective refusal to adopt
measures
to prevent anticompetitive manipulations of IEEE processes. Grounds
for
real concern on those fronts can be found in (a) United States
v.
National Society of Professional Engineers, 435 U.S. 679 (1978); and
(b)
American Society of Mechanical Engineers v. Hydrolevel Corp., 456
U.S.
556 (1982).
-----Original Message-----
From: Taffet, Richard S.
[mailto:richard.taffet@BINGHAM.COM]
Sent: Friday, March 10, 2006 3:32 PM
To:
PP-DIALOG@LISTSERV.IEEE.ORG
Subject: Re: [PP-DIALOG] Application of per se
rule to ex ante joint
conduct
Gil
Thank you for your
comments.
First, it may be that your perspective is focused narrowly on
the agenda
posted for the March 27 meeting. If so, I can see how you are
having
trouble in understanding how the Golden Bridges decision may have
an
impact on discussions at the IEEE PatCom, and how the decision may
cause
some concern even with the issues that have been teed up for the
next
meeting.
However, we certainly have no control over how the
agenda is set, or how
the PatCom is going to tackle all of the issues that
have been raised
over the past 9 to 10 months. As you commented yesterday,
neither you
nor I have any vote in what the PatCom does, and the Chair has
made it
clear that he is not bound to abide by any consensus of
interested
parties. Accordingly, I think it is very important for all
interested
parties and the IEEE organization to be sensitive to how specific
issues
that might be on the instant agenda will lead to the discussion
of
future issues that have already been identified and proposed
for
discussion. Included in this group of issues that may be discussed
in
the future is a policy that would have license terms decided by
"[a]
group of licensees negotiating collectively with owners of
competiting
technologies." (source: June 2005 submission to DOJ and FTC). As
you
pointed out in connection with that possibility there may be
competitive
justifications for that type of arrangements, but whether there
are or
not would not change the fact that a per se antitrust claim could
be
asserted in connection with such conduct, and depending on the
pleading
such a claim could very easily survive a motion to dismiss, or
applying
the Golden Bridges' type of reasoning a motion for summary
judgment.
So, I think it is reasonable to consider specific proposals
that may be
discussed early in the process for some reason in the context of
the
broader proposals that have been made and which underlie this effort.
I
do not think it is too far of a stretch to think that there is some
plan
to establish positions, for example in connection with the LoA,
that
will then compel policy changes that might not otherwise be supported
if
addressed in the first instance from a full policy position.
Indeed,
the email from the PatCom chair to Larry Bassuk yesterday, as
I
understand it, says exactly this -- that the LoA is not intended to
be
amended to reflect current policy, but is to be used to drive
future
changes in the policy. I am not sure why it is not a
legitimate
comment, as I believe Larry made, to suggest that this is not a
proper
approach, but the Chair has indicated that he will not entertain
such
discussion. Putting aside whether this procedural step itself,
coupled
with the indication that decisions will not be made based on a
consensus
of interested parties, raises some issues, including as might
be
asserted under an Allied Tube analysis, it does suggest that there
may
be some strategy that is being pursued to progress the IEEE policy
to
include matters not identified on the March 27 agenda.
Included in
such later to be addressed issues may be your proposal for
collective
negotiation of license terms. Whether such collective
negotiations occur ex
ante (as I assume you would prefer) or ex post, it
would seem not to matter
for the Golden Bridges' decision apply.
Similarly, mandatory rate caps,
which have also been proposed and is on
the agenda for the March 27 meeting,
may foster a far greater likelihood
of claims such as is the subject of the
Golden Bridges case. Here, too,
I think you would agree from the perspective
of antitrust counselling
that while justifications may be offered, the
practical fact that even a
rule providing for voluntary rate caps could lead
to uncontrolled
discussions (outside the meeting room as alleged in Golden
Bridges) that
then are implemented in the meeting to set rates collectively.
Again,
the fact that justifications may exist and that a rule of
reason
analysis should be applied, or that the rule is nominally voluntary,
is
not going to stop a claim from being asserted or the possibility of
a
court rejecting the justifications and application of the rule
of
reason. That risk, which as illustrated by Golden Bridges (as well
as
the Conexant case in which TI prevailed but was still required
to
litigate) is not fanciful or remote.
When viewed in context the
issue of whether to include the definition of
"reasonable rates, terms and
conditions" as proposed, or any definition
of what
reasonable rates and license terms will be, in an LoA also could
give rise to
what may be alleged as a garden variety per se unlawful
antitrust violation.
The proposed definition is particularly problematic
because it would impose a
standard upon patent owners that is not
supported by law. Notwithstanding
that some commentators, as identified
by Scott Peterson, have discussed that
from economists perspective it is
possible to identify value attributable to
a patent itself and an
additional amount to the fact that the patented
technology is
standardized, this assessment is not universally accepted, and
it is the
very rare commentator that has suggested that patent owners should
be
stripped of the value of their IP based upon such an analysis.
Nor
would this theory apply in each case, as you have acknowledged,
for
example where there is only a single patented alternative
under
consideration for standardization. Such a step, even in the
standards
context, also would be fundamentally contrary to patent
law.
Accordingly, it is certainly conceivable that one could allege that
an
SDOs adoption of such a rule constitutes concerted action
(especially
where consensus is not the basis for the decision). Moreover,
because
the proposed definition only includes selective factors, and not
many
other factors that would be relevant to a full determination of what
a
willing licensor and willing licensee would agree to at the time of
the
negotiations, it could be argued too that it is equivalent to a
price
fixing agreement. Again, the purpose of this point is not to say
that
such a claim would necessarily succeed, but rather to point out that
it
may survive a motion to dismiss. This may not be a Golden Bridges'
type
allegation, but I don't think the IEEE should be limiting itself to
only
those type of antitrust theories. (This comment also does not
address
the fact that in my view, wearing an SDO hat, this is just bad
policy
because it would impose a rigid definition that is not applicable
to
many situations that arise in the standards process.)
Likewise,
although not related to the Golden Bridges' decision, the
approach of the LoA
is problematic because it could have the exact
contrary effect than I had
thought was intended. Rather than providing
information early in the
standards development process, it could result
in causing patent owners to
wait until the very last minute to disclose
IP and to submit an LoA. This
likelihood is already more probable than
not because of the fact that any LoA
will not be binding and
irrevocable. The very real problem is that it may be
impossible to
identify what is an "essential patent" until the standard is
well along
the way to being final. Accordingly, unless a patent owner wishes
to
give a blanket license (which as proposed would apply to all
essential
patents whether disclosed or not, which itself reflects a
fundamental
change from the ANSI policy), it runs the risk of having to
make
licensing commitments without even knowing whether its IP is
essential.
If such IP is then subjected to a collective negotiation of terms
or
mandatory rate caps, prices for non-essential competing patents would
be
fixed as would rates for essential patents. I think you do
understand
the potential antitrust risk there.
Similarly, the proposed
LoA's approach to Organizational Knowledge could
exacerbate these problems,
especially for companies that themselves are
not members, but who's employees
are members. How would the concept of
Organizational Knowledge as proposed
even apply in that circumstance?
Further, how could an employee who has
nothing to do with licensing
issues or his employer's patent portfolio be in
a position to bind his
company, much less affiliates, successors and
assigns?
Further, the proposal to make the LoA binding by having it
signed by the
IEEE also involves antitrust issues. Such a step clearly would
allow
the argument that the concerted action element of a Section 1
Sherman
Act claim is satisfied, and any anticompetitive effects achieved
through
implementation of the LoAs, especially under a rule of reason
analysis,
would require extensive analysis, and resulting costs and
times.
I hope these comments help you. Please understand they are not
being
offered for any purpose other than to express what I believe may
result
in less efficient, and thereby less procompetitive,
standards
development. These are my views regarding the standards process,
and
should not be ascribed to any particular company that I may or may
not
represent. I hope you take them in that way, and that you do not
think
that they are offered to counterbalance your positions. I do think
it
would be a very bad result, however, if rules are adopted, no matter
how
well intentioned, that will not accommodate all stakeholders'
interests
in the IEEE type of open standards body, and that will give rise to
even
the prospect of greater litigation risks, to say nothing of
liability
risks. I think this would be especially unfortunate if such rules
are
adopted because of a flawed process or a failure to consider all of
the
very complex variables that exists in standards development, as well
as
in connection with the current state of technology, competition
and
licensing.
Look forward to seeing you soon.
Richard
S. Taffet, Esq.
Bingham McCutchen LLP
399 Park Avenue
New York, New
York 10022-4689
T: (212) 705-7729
F: (212) 702-3603
email:
richard.taffet@bingham.com
cell: (914) 582-2477
-----Original
Message-----
From: Gil Ohana (gilohana) [mailto:gilohana@cisco.com]
Sent: Thursday, March 09, 2006 7:27 PM
To: Taffet, Richard S.;
PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: RE: [PP-DIALOG] Application of per se
rule to ex ante joint
conduct
Thanks Richard. I'm not aware that
the issue of royalty caps, which as
we both know is alive in ETSI, is on the
IEEE-SA agenda. I'm also not
aware that the rules changes that PatCom is
being asked to consider, as
you put it, "rules that will invariably (at least
allegedly) lead to
fixing of license terms by joint conduct." PatCom is being
asked to
consider rules that will give patricipants in standard-setting
and
implementers of IEEE standards more information about what terms
they
will have to accept to practice those standards. I'm missing how
that
leads to "fixing of license terms."
On your suggestion regarding
agenda efficiency and the views you ask me
to present, all I can say in
response is that it was you, not me, that
posted the Golden Bridge opinion in
what could be seen as an attempt to
raise in the minds of PatCom members the
specter of antitrust risk as a
reason not to favor the ex ante proposals.
Further to my prior postings
in response, perhaps you can make your reasoning
explicit. You are a
leading practitioner that has been engaged in
standard-setting and
antitrust issues since for a while, and your views
would, I'm sure, be
illuminating.
Gil Ohana
Director, Antitrust and
Competition
Cisco Systems, Inc.
300 E. Tasman Drive
MS 10/2
San
Jose, CA 95134
United States of America
Phone: +1 408 525 2853
Mobile:
+1 408 203 5301
E-mail: gilohana@cisco.com
-----Original
Message-----
From: Taffet, Richard S. [mailto:richard.taffet@bingham.com]
Sent: Thursday, March 09, 2006 3:44 PM
To: Gil
Ohana (gilohana); PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: RE:
[PP-DIALOG] Application of per se rule to ex ante joint
conduct
I
certainly agree wholeheartedly with your point that it is important
to
consider how enforcement agencies will consider changes in SDO
rules.
Some may be positive and some may be negative, as I understand has
been
the reaction of the EC officials to certain positions in ETSI.
I
am not too concerned with agenda efficiency, however. I am more
concerned
that whomever is making the decision does so on a fully
informed basis and
not to advance a specific agenda.
I think specifically when you get into
issues such as royalty caps, and
rules that will invariably (at least
allegedly) lead to fixing of
license terms by joint conduct, grave concerns
should exist.
Likewise, I would think that if agenda efficiency is the
primary
motivating factor here, please do share with us your views how each
of
the proposals that have been made will not conclusively allow any
claim
of concerted action or an anticompetitive effect. If you can do that
by
first of next week, we will have a basis to continue the
dialog.
Richard S. Taffet, Esq.
Bingham McCutchen LLP
399 Park
Avenue
New York, New York 10022-4689
T: (212) 705-7729
F: (212)
702-3603
email: richard.taffet@bingham.com
cell: (914)
582-2477
-----Original Message-----
From: Gil Ohana (gilohana)
[mailto:gilohana@cisco.com]
Sent: Thursday, March 09, 2006 6:17 PM
To:
Taffet, Richard S.; PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: RE: [PP-DIALOG]
Application of per se rule to ex ante joint
conduct
Thanks
Richard. For better or worse, neither of us is a member of the
Patent
Committee. I'm hoping that the people that actually get to do
the voting are
monitoring this list, and they would benefit from hearing
your views as to
why the specific legal theory asserted by the plaintiff
in the Golden Bridge
case you chose to post to the list is relevant to
the votes they will be
asked to cast on the 27th. They also may benefit
from understanding more
generally, particularly in the wake of the
various statements regarding the
issue of ex ante disclosure rules and
antitrust risks that have been made by
the European Commission and the
leadership of both US federal antitrust
agencies, what role
consideration of antitrust risk should play in their
consideration of
the various proposals for the changes to the IEEE-SA rules
involving ex
ante disclosure of licensing comitments.
That is not an
easy question, and it merits careful consideration from
the members of PatCom
(after all, if you're right about the connection
you seem to posit between
between ex ante rules and increased antitrust
risk, then IEEE-SA would seem
to have a significant organizational
interest at stake in avoiding the "messy
and unpredictable" process of
antitrust
litigation). I'm hoping that you share my goal of addressing
those issues in
advance of the meeting so that we can proceed through
the agenda
efficiently.
Best regards,
Gil Ohana
Director, Antitrust and
Competition
Cisco Systems, Inc.
300 E. Tasman Drive
MS
10/2
San Jose, CA 95134
United States of America
Phone: +1 408 525
2853
Mobile: +1 408 203 5301
E-mail:
gilohana@cisco.com
-----Original Message-----
From: Taffet,
Richard S. [mailto:richard.taffet@bingham.com]
Sent: Thursday, March 09, 2006 2:57 PM
To: Gil Ohana (gilohana);
PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: RE: [PP-DIALOG] Application of per se
rule to ex ante joint
conduct
Gil
What's your rush? What
conclusions will you draw? I am not sure what
the basis will be to conclude
anything one way or the other, or what
signficance it will have in what the
IEEE is considering on the merits.
If there is a need for you to find out
more information on a particular
schedule, give me a call and we can schedule
a time to discuss each of
the proposals and each of their implications. If it
is important to
you, we can try to schedule such a call in advance of the
March 27
meeting Let me know.
Richard S. Taffet, Esq.
Bingham
McCutchen LLP
399 Park Avenue
New York, New York 10022-4689
T: (212)
705-7729
F: (212) 702-3603
email: richard.taffet@bingham.com
cell:
(914) 582-2477
-----Original Message-----
From: Gil Ohana
(gilohana) [mailto:gilohana@cisco.com]
Sent: Thursday, March 09, 2006 5:28 PM
To: Taffet, Richard S.;
PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: RE: [PP-DIALOG] Application of per se
rule to ex ante joint
conduct
Richard, why wait for the meeting?
You have the chance to enlighten all
of us now.
To frame the question
again, I'm not asking you generally for your view
of why ex ante disclosure
rules increase the risk that SDOs and
companies participating in
standard-setting will face antiturst
ligitation. I'm going back to the Golden
Bridge decision you chose to
bring to the attention to the list and asking
you to explain which of
the specific rules changes that IEEE-SA's Patent
Committee would
increase the risk that IEEE-SA or participants in IEEE-SA's
technical
working groups would face group refusal to deal claims. It's a
simple
enough question, and if your response is that you'll need all the
time
between now and March 27 to think of an answer, then we'll draw
the
appropriate conclusions. I'm optimistic (there I go again) that
we
won't have to wait that long.
Gil Ohana
Director, Antitrust
and Competition
Cisco Systems, Inc.
300 E. Tasman Drive
MS 10/2
San
Jose, CA 95134
United States of America
Phone: +1 408 525
2853
Mobile: +1 408 203 5301
E-mail:
gilohana@cisco.com
-----Original Message-----
From: Taffet,
Richard S. [mailto:richard.taffet@BINGHAM.COM]
Sent: Thursday, March 09, 2006 2:14 PM
To:
PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: Re: [PP-DIALOG] Application of per se
rule to ex ante joint
conduct
I am sure the PatCom chair will afford
us plenty of time to discuss how
the IEEE proposals could raise the same type
of claims as alleged in the
Golden Bridges case. I think you are also truly
the optimist in
thinking that rules, which have already engendered
significant debate
when merely being proposed, will lead to anything but more
litigation.
Words have a funny way of being interpreted in interesting ways
in the
context of lawsuits.
Richard S. Taffet, Esq.
Bingham
McCutchen LLP
399 Park Avenue
New York, New York 10022-4689
T: (212)
705-7729
F: (212) 702-3603
email: richard.taffet@bingham.com
cell:
(914) 582-2477
-----Original Message-----
From: Gil Ohana
(gilohana) [mailto:gilohana@cisco.com]
Sent: Thursday, March 09, 2006 5:10 PM
To: Taffet, Richard S.;
PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: RE: [PP-DIALOG] Application of per se
rule to ex ante joint
conduct
Thanks Richard. Recognizing your
point that the 3GPP standards are
being revised, what Golden Bridge has
alleged is a group refusal to deal
by a number of large potential licensees,
effectuated through an
informal agreement reached in what the opinion terms
is an "offline
session." I'm still not seeing the connection between any of
the
proposed rules changes that IEEE-SA is considering and the
conduct
alleged in Golden Bridge. Nothing about, for example,
permitting
patentees disclosing essential patents to an IEEE-SA working group
to
state a "not to exceed" royalty or attaching to their LoA a
binding
licensing commitment would in any way increase the exposure that
IEEE-SA
or participants in IEEE-SA working groups face under the antitrust
laws
from the kinds of claim asserted by Golden Bridge.
So I go back
to the point made in my earlier e-mail: are you just trying
to remind us that
participants in standard-setting face antitrust risk?
Or are you trying to
argue that there is something specific in the
proposed IEEE-SA rules changes
that the Patent Committee is to consider
in a few weeks that increases the
risk IEEE-SA and participants in
IEEE-SA standards working groups face from
group refusal to deal claims?
It's easy enough to mention ex ante and
antitrust risk in the same
sentence and hope that people associate the two.
But, after the
endorsement of ex ante disclosure rules provided both in
Chairman
Majoras' speech and in the press release the European Commission
issued
in December following the change to ETSI's rules, it would be helpful
to
the debate if you could provide a more specific causal linkage
between
the rules that IEEE-SA is considering adopting and increased
antitrust
risk to IEEE-SA or its members.
One more thing: I agree with
you that litigation is "messy and
unpredictable." Of course, a major benefit
of the adoption of ex ante
rules is that they avoid the need for companies
seeking to implement a
standard to avoid the need to litigate patent disputes
with patentees
that seek to define what a "reasonable" royalty is
expansively. Those
cases, too, can be "messy and unpredictable."
Gil
Ohana
Director, Antitrust and Competition
Cisco Systems, Inc.
300 E.
Tasman Drive
MS 10/2
San Jose, CA 95134
United States of
America
Phone: +1 408 525 2853
Mobile: +1 408 203 5301
E-mail:
gilohana@cisco.com
-----Original Message-----
From:
Taffet, Richard S. [mailto:richard.taffet@bingham.com]
Sent: Thursday, March 09, 2006 1:45 PM
To: Gil Ohana (gilohana);
PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: RE: [PP-DIALOG] Application of per se
rule to ex ante joint
conduct
Not sure your very careful attempt to
distinguish the import of this
case from the discussion of joint ex ante is
terribly meaningful, or
would be found persuasive by either a court or a
plaintiff's lawyer who
seeks to address ex ante conduct that eliminates the
inclusion of a
patented technology in a standard or deprives a patent owner
of
flexibility in licensing terms. Not suggesting that the allegations
of
the case have merit, but there are quite a number of companies that
now are
spending a lot of money and time litigating for what might be
considered
competitively benign conduct.
Happy to discuss these points further, but
one fact I think you will
agree is that especially in the 3GPP context,
standards are continuously
being revised, and there is no simple conclusion
that can be reached
when a standard is final. So, in connection with this
specific case,
the elimination of of Golden Bridge's technology was part of
the
evolution of the 3GPP standard.
Accordingly, the key take away
might be that nice theories can always be
justified, but legal claims and
litigation are messy and unpredictable
-- which leads to high costs and less
efficiency in standards
development.
Speak to you soon.
Richard
S. Taffet, Esq.
Bingham McCutchen LLP
399 Park Avenue
New York, New
York 10022-4689
T: (212) 705-7729
F: (212) 702-3603
email:
richard.taffet@bingham.com
cell: (914) 582-2477
-----Original
Message-----
From: Gil Ohana (gilohana) [mailto:gilohana@cisco.com]
Sent: Thursday, March 09, 2006 4:34 PM
To: Taffet,
Richard S.; PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: RE: [PP-DIALOG] Application
of per se rule to ex ante joint
conduct
Richard, thank you for
providing the Golden Bridge opinion. As I read
the opinion, it stands for the
(uncontroversial) position that a group
refusal to deal among competitors
that collectively have market power
can violate Section 1 of the Sherman Act.
Aside from the fact that the
particular group refusal to deal alleged
happened in the context of
standard-setting, I'm having trouble understanding
how the case relates
to (as the title of your e-mail states) "ex ante joint
conduct". Per
the facts of the opinion, the discussion among the defendants
that led
to Golden Bridge's technology being dropped as an optional feature
of
the 3GPP standard occurred after the 3GPP standard had already
been
approved by 3GPP. See Opinion at 2 ("In 1999 cPCH [Golden
Bridge's
patented technology] was adopted by 3GPP as an optional part of the
3GPP
standard."). The allegedly anticompetitive acts Golden Brdge
is
complaining of did not occur until years later.
If your goal is to
remind participants in IEEE standard-setting that
antitrust issues swirl
around standard-setting, then the Golden Bridge
opionion is a useful reminder
of that point. But if (as I suspect from
the title of your e-mail) your goal
is to suggest that the antitrust
risks standards bodies or their participants
face are increased by the
adoption of those bodies of ex ante disclosure
rules, then I must admit
that the support the Golden Bridge opinion provides
for that proposition
is escaping me.
Gil Ohana
Director, Antitrust
and Competition
Cisco Systems, Inc.
300 E. Tasman Drive
MS 10/2
San
Jose, CA 95134
United States of America
Phone: +1 408 525 2853
Mobile:
+1 408 203 5301
E-mail: gilohana@cisco.com
-----Original
Message-----
From: Taffet, Richard S. [mailto:richard.taffet@BINGHAM.COM]
Sent: Thursday, March 09, 2006 11:27 AM
To:
PP-DIALOG@listserv.ieee.org
Subject: [PP-DIALOG] Application of per se rule
to ex ante joint conduct
The recent decision from the United States
District Court for the
Eastern District of Texas is another example where
joint ex ante
standards conduct relating to IP was alleged to violate the
antitrust
laws, including under a per se theory. In this case, defendants'
motion
for summary judgment was denied, including on the ground that per
se
treatment might be appropriate. Even without the issue of whether
the
conduct should be considered under a per se or rule of reason
approach,
the fact is the case is now going to trial and will involve all of
the
costs and uncertainties that necessarily
result.
<<show_case_doc.pdf>>
Richard S. Taffet,
Esq.
Bingham McCutchen LLP
399 Park Avenue
New York, New York
10022-4689
T: (212) 705-7729
F: (212) 702-3603
email:
richard.taffet@bingham.com
cell: (914)
582-2477
========================================================================
====
Bingham
McCutchen LLP Circular 230 Notice: To ensure compliance with
IRS
requirements, we inform you that any U.S. federal tax advice
contained in
this communication is not intended or written to be used,
and cannot be used
by any taxpayer, for the purpose of avoiding any
federal tax penalties. Any
legal advice expressed in this message is
being delivered to you solely for
your use in connection with the
matters addressed herein and may not be
relied upon by any other person
or entity or used for any other purpose
without our prior
written
consent.
========================================================================
====
------------------------------------------------------------------------
---------------
Disclaimer
Required by IRS Rules of Practice:
Any discussion of tax matters contained
herein is not intended or
written to be used, and cannot be used, for the
purpose of avoiding any
penalties that may be imposed under Federal tax
laws.
------------------------------------------------------------------------
---------------
This
message contains information which may be confidential and
privileged. Unless
you are the intended addressee (or authorized to
receive for the intended
addressee), you may not use, copy or disclose
to anyone the message or any
information contained in the message. If
you have received the message in
error, please advise the sender by
reply at e-mail@dbr.com and delete the
message.
Thank you very
much.
------------------------------------------------------------------------
------------